Supported by
Guest Essay
America Is Sleepwalking Into an Economic Storm
Daron Acemoglu, a professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, received the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences this year.
Inflation seems under control. The job market remains healthy. Wages, including at the bottom end of the scale, are rising. But this is just a lull. There is a storm approaching, and Americans are not prepared.
Barreling toward us are three epochal changes poised to reshape the U.S. economy in coming years: an aging population, the rise of artificial intelligence and the rewiring of the global economy.
There should be little surprise in this, since all these are evolving slowly in plain sight. What has not been fully understood is how these changes in combination are likely to transform the lives of working people in ways not seen since the late 1970s, when wage inequality surged and wages at the low end stagnated or even fell.
Together, if handled correctly, these challenges could remake work and deliver much higher productivity, wages and opportunities — something the computer revolution promised and never fulfilled. If we mismanage the moment, they could make good, well-paying jobs scarcer and the economy less dynamic. Our decisions over the next five to 10 years will determine which path we take.
Our dysfunctional political system, which is increasingly short-termist in its vision for the country, is unlikely to prepare us for these changes. Neither Vice President Kamala Harris nor former President Donald Trump is focusing on them with any seriousness in their election campaigns. Nor do we see comprehensive plans from either party to make the investments necessary to equip the American work force to deal with the coming challenges.
The U.S. work force has never aged like this. In 2000, there were about 27 Americans above the age of 65 for every 100 Americans of prime working age (between the ages of 20 and 49). By 2020, this number had increased to 39. By 2040, it will have risen to 54. Because these changes are driven mostly by a decline in fertility, the U.S. work force will also soon begin to grow more slowly. If immigration into the United States is reduced, as seems likely no matter who wins the election, this will only contribute to the aging problem.
Many jobs in the economy, such as in manufacturing and construction, require physical strength and stamina, which start declining as an individual ages, even with the kinds of health improvements we’ve seen. Workers typically reach peak productivity in their 40s. The young are also more entrepreneurial and willing to take risks, which many economies, not least America’s, sorely need.
Over the past three decades, Japan, Germany and South Korea have aged almost twice as rapidly as the United States is aging right now, which means we have models to follow. The good news is that their economies have not grown more slowly than those of other industrialized nations and that several of their labor-dependent sectors, including cars, machine tools and chemicals, haven’t suffered.
The reason is simple: They introduced new machinery, including industrial robots and other automation technologies, to take over the tasks younger employees would have performed. These countries also invested in training workers so that they could take on the new tasks that complement automation. German carmakers retrained their blue-collar workers for more technical tasks such as repair, quality control and digital machine operation, while they rolled out robots. As a result, productivity has surged, and wages have continued to increase.
There’s a scenario in which a shortage of labor could be a boon for the U.S. economy. Wages for lower-educated workers stagnated or even declined between 1980 and the mid-2010s. Scarcity of labor can drive wages up, especially if combined with the right investments in both equipment and people.
Alas, this isn’t what is happening in the United States. Investment in robots has increased rapidly, but it hasn’t been accompanied by adequate investments in people. The work force remains unready for taking on new tasks, including technical and advanced precision work. It was the shortage of these types of skills that the Taiwan Semiconductor Manufacturing Factory cited as a reason for delays in the opening of its first U.S.-based chip factory. If the United States doesn’t find ways to combine new machinery with better-trained, more-skilled and more-adaptable workers, the country risks more pain for manufacturing, the traditional provider of high-wage, stable jobs.
There are similar opportunities, also likely to be wasted, when it comes to artificial intelligence. According to its most ardent fans, A.I. is the mother of all technological disruptions, the apogee of the digital age. Yet when you strip away the hype surrounding superintelligent algorithms, the A.I. challenge is remarkably similar to that of adapting to aging.
A.I. is an information technology. It will not make your cake or mow your lawn. Nor will it take over the running of companies or scientific inquiry. Rather, it can automate a range of cognitive tasks that are typically performed in offices or in front of a computer. It can also provide better information to human decision makers — perhaps one day, much better.
None of this will happen rapidly. As of February 2024, only about 5 percent of businesses in the United States have reported using A.I., and the technology itself is far from perfect (Google’s A.I. struggled initially with questions about whether it’s smart to eat rocks). Its spread in the economy will be slow, and its true impact won’t be felt until the mid-2030s. The nature of that impact will depend on the readiness of corporations and workers.
We need a broad national strategy so that A.I. doesn’t only automate work and sideline workers but also creates new tasks and competencies for them. This isn’t just because of the inequality that rapid A.I.-based automation could create or the fear of tech elites that the resulting joblessness will bring out the pitchforks. Evidence suggests that new technologies increase productivity much more consistently when they work with workers, enabling them to perform their jobs better and take on new, more sophisticated tasks. The secret sauce of Henry Ford’s innovative car factories wasn’t simply a more widespread use of better machinery but also a whole range of technical tasks that workers were trained for, such as repair and maintenance.
Most of us today are involved in problem-solving, whether an office worker making loan or hiring decisions, a scientist or journalist trying to get to the bottom of a question or an electrician, carpenter or craft worker dealing with malfunctions and other real-world obstacles. Most of us can become more productive and expand our range if we get better information.
Yet, even more than with aging, it looks like we’re going to mismanage this wave. The industry is locked into a race centered on “artificial general intelligence,” meaning the inchoate dream of producing machines that are just like humans and can take over all tasks from us. It remains preoccupied with using this technology either for generating digital ad revenue or for automation.
The real promise of A.I. is unlikely to become reality by itself. It requires A.I. models to become more expert, better powered by higher-quality data, more reliable and more aligned with the existing knowledge and the information-processing capabilities of workers. None of this appears to be at the top of Big Tech’s agenda.
One obvious policy to confront both the aging and the A.I. challenges is to encourage training of workers — for example, with tax credits or training subsidies, so that they can take on new tasks and jobs. Ms. Harris’s economic plan puts much more emphasis on this than Mr. Trump’s. Much more can be done.
It isn’t just that workers need to get ready. So do our technological capabilities. Here the federal government can play an important role, for example via a new federal agency tasked with identifying and funding the types of A.I. that can increase worker productivity and help us deal with looming labor shortages.
Globalization may seem like a different kettle of fish, but there are major parallels. The era of rapid and largely unfettered globalization that followed the collapse of the Soviet Union is over. It benefited Western consumers and multinational corporations, which got access to inexpensive labor overseas. Workers, not so much.
What will replace globalization is less clear. It could be a fragmented system, in which countries trade with allies and friends, with broadly similar flows to what we are seeing today (say, less of China and more of Vietnam). It could be one with high tariffs and much less trade. It could also be a combination of trade restrictions and industrial policies, such as the Biden administration’s Inflation Reduction Act and CHIPS Act, which are designed to encourage more investment and manufacturing, especially in advanced electronics, electric cars and renewable technologies, to stay in or to relocate to the United States.
This change is also slow and has significant implications for workers. The promise of new manufacturing capabilities could lead to new job opportunities and possibly higher wages. On the other hand, new manufacturing competencies cannot be built overnight, and skills shortages can choke off industrial renewal. Alas, once again, the United States, especially its work force, isn’t ready.
The good news here is that we have time, and if we grab the opportunities presented by aging, A.I. and the new globalization, they can all serve to improve one another. The skills that employers and schools need to tackle each of these huge shifts are similar. Moreover, the right kind of A.I. can greatly help us navigate the challenges posed by aging and the reshaping of globalization.
The bad news is that these issues are not getting the attention they deserve, even though they are much more important for our future than debates about price gouging, taxes on tips or whether inflation is one point higher or one point lower. Unless we focus on them and act decisively, they will not just be mismanaged but also may spell a more dire future of work.
Daron Acemoglu is a professor at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, a co-author of “Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty” and a recipient of the 2024 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, shared with two other academic researchers, Simon Johnson and James Robinson.
The Times is committed to publishing a diversity of letters to the editor. We’d like to hear what you think about this or any of our articles. Here are some tips. And here’s our email: letters@nytimes.com.
Follow the New York Times Opinion section on Facebook, Instagram, TikTok, WhatsApp, X and Threads.
An earlier version of this article misstated the number of Americans of prime working age compared with those age 65 or over in three ratios. The ratios are per 100 workers, not for every one worker.
When we learn of a mistake, we acknowledge it with a correction. If you spot an error, please let us know at nytnews@nytimes.com.Learn more
Advertisement
No comments:
Post a Comment